A peer-reviewed open-access journal NeoBiota 31: 19-41 (2016) doi: 10.3897/neobiota.3 1.8103 @) NeoBiota http:/ / neob iota. pen soft. net Advancing research on alien species and biological invasions A cost-benefit analysis of controlling giant hogweed (Heracleum mantegazzianum) in Germany using a choice experiment approach Sandra Rajmis', Jan Thiele’, Rainer Marggraf? | Julius Kiihn-Institut (]K1), Federal Research Centre for Cultivated Plants, Institute for Strategies and Techno- logy Assessment, Stahnsdorfer Damm 81, 14532 Kleinmachnow, Germany 2 Westfalische Wilhelms-Univer- sitét Minster, Institute of Landscape Ecology, Heisenbergstrafse 2, 48149 Miinster, Germany 3 Georg-August- Universitat Gottingen, Department for Agricultural Economics and Rural Development, Platz der Gottinger Sieben 5, 37073 Gottingen, Germany Corresponding author: Sandra Rajmis (sandra.rajmis@julius-kuehn.de) Academic editor: Franz Essl | Received 10 February 2016 | Accepted 30 May 2016 | Published 14 September 2016 Citation: Rajmis S, Thiele J, Marggraf R (2016) A cost-benefit analysis of controlling giant hogweed (Heracleum mantegazzianum) in Germany using a choice experiment approach. NeoBiota 31: 19-41. doi: 10.3897/neobiota.31.8103 Abstract Since first of January 2015, the EU-regulation 1143/2014 obligates all member states to conduct cost- benefit analyses in preparation of control programs for invasive alien species to minimize and mitigate their impacts. In addition, with ratification of the Rio Declaration and the amended Federal Nature Conservation Act, Germany is committed to control any further spread of invasive species. This is the first cost-benefit analysis estimating positive welfare effects and societal importance of H. mantagezzianum in- vasion control in Germany. The paper analyses possible control options limiting stands of giant hogweeds (H.. mantegazzianum) based on survey data of n = 287 German districts. We differentiate between several control options (e.g. root destruction, mechanical cutting or mowing, chemical treatment and grazing) depending on infested area size and protection status. The calculation of benefits is based on stated prefer- ence results (choice experiment; n = 282). For the cost side, we calculate two different invasion scenarios (i) no re-infestation after successfully conducted control measures (optimistic) and (ii) re-infestation twice after conducting control measures occurring within ten years (pessimistic). Minimum costs of eradication measures including a time span of ten years and a social discount rate of 1% result in a total of 3,467,640 € for optimistic scenario and 6,254,932 € for pessimistic invasion scenario, where no success of the first eradication attempt is assumed. Benefits of invasion control in Germany result in a total of 238,063,641 € per year and overassessment-factor corrected in 59,515,910 € per year. Copyright Sandra Rajmis et al. This is an open access article distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License (CC BY 4.0), which permits unrestricted use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original author and source are credited. 20 Sandra Rajmis et al. / NeoBiota 31: 19-41 (2016) Keywords Invasive species, giant hogweed, control measures, cost-benefit analysis, willingness to pay (WTP) Introduction Invasive species are considered to be a primary driver of biodiversity loss across the globe (UNEP 2015). Results of invasion experiments indicate that the loss of species may have profound effects on the integrity and functioning of ecosystems (see e.g. Mwangi et al. 2007, van Ruijven et al. 2003, Pfisterer et al. 2004). In addition, invasive species cause public health concerns (EEA 2012, EPPO 2009, Bundesamt ftir Naturschutz 2015). Currently, about 10 million € are spent annually in Germany for control measures of invasive plant species and about one million € only for health-treatment expenses (Bun- desamt ftir Naturschutz 2015, Reinhardt et al. 2003). H. mantegazzianum is originally an endemic species of the sub-alpine zone in the Western Greater Caucasus. It was in- troduced to Central Europe as an ornamental plant in the 19° century (Pysek 1991, Starfinger and Kowarik 2003, Pergl et al. 2012). Beekeepers established giant hogweed as fodder plant (Westhus et al. 2006). Currently, H. mantegazzianum is spread all over Europe (Nehring et al. 2013a, Pergl et al. 2012, Kowarik 2010); and in Germany, H. mantegazzianum currently occupies 68 % of grid cells of the national floristic map (Net- PhyD and BfN 2013). Field studies in Germany’ revealed a high variability of cover- abundances; about one third of surveyed stands were dominant’ with cover-abundances exceeding 50% (Thiele and Otte 2008). H. mantegazzianum occurs in a variety of dif- ferent habitat types, such as roadsides, grasslands, riparian habitats and woodland mar- gins (Thiele and Otte 2006). The highest invasion percentage (18.5%) was found for abandoned grasslands, field and grassland margins and tall-forb stands (Thiele and Otte 2008). Open stands generally prevailed over dominant ones and single stands with sizes between 100 and 1,000 m* occurred most frequently (145 of 233 stands) while stands larger than 1,000 m? were found as minority (32 of 233 stands; Thiele and Otte 2008). H.. mantegazzianum has impacts on biodiversity through competitive displacement of native plant species, particularly at abandoned sites (Thiele et al. 2010), although this seems not a serious threat to protected habitats or regional diversity (Bundesamt fiir Naturschutz 2015). More attention has to be drawn on the health risk to humans (Bundesamt ftir Naturschutz 2015, Maguire et al. 2008, Hipkin 1991, Camm et al. 1976, Drever and Hunter 1970). The species is dangerous to humans because it ex- udes a clear watery sap, containing several chemical agents (e.g. furocoumarins) which sensitise human skin and lead to severe blistering when exposed to sunlight (Drever ' The quoted field studies were conducted in 2001 at 16 German sites at the Western Low Mountain Ranges (Thiele and Otte 2008). The observed limitations indicate only partly dominant stands in the future, namely those represent- ing early habitat invasion and disturbances or land-use change (Thiele and Otte 2008). A cost-benefit analysis of controlling giant hogweed (Heracleum mantegazzianum)... 21 and Hunter 1970, Hipkin 1991). Blisters can take up to twenty four hours to appear and the entire reaction can recur for many years (Maguire et al. 2008). In addition to the health hazard, occurrence of H. mantegazzianum can limit public accessibility of sites, trails and amenity areas (Tiley and Philp 1994). Besides, it bears the risk to cause ecological damages, e.g. erosion at riverbanks (PySek 1991). With entering into force, the EU-regulation 1143/2014 obligates member states to develop concrete action plans (including timetables for action, description of the measures to be adopted, voluntary actions, codes of good practice) to limit (further) spread of invasive alien species into or within the European Union. After establishing a national list of invasive alien species of concern, member states have eighteen month for comprehensive cost-benefit analysis of pathways and spread and three years for the implementation of one single action plan (European Commission 2014). Appropriate monitoring needs to be planned to reduce density and abundance of invasive species and to keep its impact to an acceptable level (Emerton and Howard 2008, Genovesi and Shine 2003). However, life-cycle variation between stand types makes it difficult to infer simple management rules (Hiils et al. 2007). Small and open stands of H. mantegazzianum may eventually serve as initiators for further spread after land-use changes, whereas dense stands might be stable (Hiils et al. 2007). Westhus et al. (2006) suggest eradica- tion of single plants or initial populations to prevent invasion of the whole area or dis- trict. Mowing or grazing are suitable for the management of grasslands and grassland- like fringe habitats (Nielsen et al. 2005, Buttenschon and Nielsen 2007) to prevent growth and any further development stages. Since the threat of giant hogweed spread towards biodiversity and the health risk for humans are recognized in Germany, there are despite some attempts of local eradication not enough efforts for spatially inclusive and comprehensive management (Nehring et al. 2013b). Increasing habitat fragmen- tation and climate change will be forcing the spread of giant hogweed if no eradication action will be undertaken (Nehring et al. 2013b). The aim of this paper is to identify costs of efficient eradication measures and their benefits to society and oppose them within a cost-benefit analysis at national level. The cost dimension covers a wide range of eradication measures with varying sizes depending on infestation share and site status in infested German districts (e.g. grazing for large area types). The benefit dimension is focused on the recreational value in terms of willingness to pay (WTP) for an environment being free of giant hogweed and its risks for humans. Current control and management of H. mantegazzianum Currently used control methods comprise a variety of manual or mechanical methods, grazing and chemical control (Nielsen et al. 2005). The probability of eradication suc- cess increases if control measures are conducted exhaustively and repeatedly within seven to ten years (Holzmann et al. 2014, Nicholas et al. 2005). The prevalence of H. mantegazzianum populations along steep embankments, in deep ravines and other 22 Sandra Rajmis et al. / NeoBiota 31: 19-41 (2016) inaccessible places makes manual treatments difficult (Nielsen et al. 2005, Nicholas et al. 2005). The current preventive control options are: ¢ Avoidance of vegetation gaps, dense vegetation cover, respectively (Pergl et al. 2007) or presence of the same functional group as invader in the endangered plant com- munity (Longo et al. 2013, Wang et al. 2013, Mwangi et al. 2007, Kahmen et al. 2005, Pokorny et al. 2005), ¢ General increase of diversity in endangered plant communities (Henry et al. 2009, Pfisterer et al. 2004, van Ruijven et al. 2003, Kennedy et al. 2002, Moore et al. 2001, Naeem et al. 2000), ¢ Low grade of human disturbance of the ‘natural’ ecosystem “degree of hemeroby’ (Mwangi et al. 2007, Machado 2004, Steinhardt et al. 1999, Jalas 1955). Recent active control options according to the literature are: ¢ Manual or mechanical control such as pulling out the whole plant by hand (EPPO 2009), root cutting or umbel removement by hand (Pysek et al. 2007a, Pysek et al. 2007b, Nielsen et al. 2005), cutting the plant from above surface with scythe, mowing or milling machines (Westhus et al. 2006, Nielsen et al. 2005), ° Grazing by sheep whereas a time frame of at least 10 years was most effective (Westhus et al. 2006, Nielsen et al. 2005, Andersen and Calov 1996, Williamson and Forbes 1982) Grazing seems meaningful for control of large stands and areas inaccessible for machinery, ¢ Chemical control whereas glyphosate’ was the most successful herbicide (Nielsen et al. 2007, Nicholas et al. 2005, EPPO 2009). To reduce damage to surrounding vegetation, applications are recommended as spot spraying early in the growing season. However, in the final calculation we suggested chemical treatment with hand-held equipment due to the lowest cost of the alternatives for medium and unprotected areas and its suitability for areas difficult to access. Revegetation programs after giant hogweed eradication are required to restore the dense vegetation layer and prevent further re-infestations successfully (Noxious Weed Control Program 2015). Basic assumptions for cost calculation of control measures Since there are only few data available for giant hogweed management in Germany, cost estimations are based on a nationwide survey of n = 287 German districts (Thie- 3 Application of glyphosate beyond agricultural fields, in critical areas or their buffers as well as in areas used for forestry has to be permitted by the nature conservation agency in charge (Paragraph 13 and 17 of German Plant Protection Act). A cost-benefit analysis of controlling giant hogweed (Heracleum mantegazzianum)... 23 Table |. Suggested measures for control of H. mantegazzianum depending on area size and protection status. Area size Root destruction with shovel Mechanical cutting with scythe Mechanical cutting with flail mower Chemical treatment with hand-held equipment Chemical treatment with | Grazing machines Unprotected areas Small (up to 100 m’) Medium (>100—1000 m7’) Large (>1000 m’) Small Medium Large le and Otte 2008) and benefit estimations are based on a choice experiment survey of n = 282 German households. The data from the survey of Thiele and Otte (2008) contain also information on population density. In detail, the questionnaire inclu- ded questions about the maximum spatial extent of single H. mantegazzianum stands in three proposed categories (up to 100 m’, >100—1,000 m’, >1,000 m/’) for diffe- rent habitat types (e.g. roadside or forest margin) and, about occurrences in nature reserves per district or city. Because no conclusion of the total frequency of single stands per district or city was possible, our calculations are based on the assumption of a minimum occurrence of the evaluated stands per district or city. This means, the available data indicate, if at /east one small, medium or large area is infested and if at least one of these areas is protected. A range of possible control measures (manual, mechanical, chemical and grazing) is identified and shown in Table 1. The crosses (X‘s) indicate meaningful applications of infestation control measures. Suggested measures are root destruction with shovel (small areas), mechanical cutting with a scythe (medium areas) or flail mower (large areas). Regarding chemical control, hand-held equipment is suitable for small and medium areas, tractors with spraying machines for large areas. Chemical treatment includes the cost of restoration such as seeds, sowing and working hours. For nature reserves, where chemical control is pro- hibited by law, we suggest root destruction with shovel (small areas) and mechanical cutting with scythe (medium and large areas). Workload, frequency and effectiveness of treatments are shown in Table 2 (based on Nielsen et al. 2005). It must be considered that chemical control has several restric- tions. Grazing is a ‘continuous treatment’ and includes the workload for fencing and maintenance. Grazing is supposed for medium and large areas, where suitable condi- tions for livestock farming are given with regard to soil and climatic conditions. 24 Sandra Rajmis et al. / NeoBiota 31: 19-41 (2016) Table 2. Estimated workload and effectiveness of different control methods. Control methods Workload area a Effectiveness treatments per year Root cutting Estimated time for control: 100 plants/hour One high Be peter gently Estimated time for control: 500 plants/hour Three low scythe erences CURRY 0.5 ha/1,000 plants/hour Three low flail mower Chemical control by : fianehliclaeqdi ements Estimated time effort: 100 plants/hour Two high Chemical control by Estimated time effort: T hich machinery 0.5 ha/1,000 plants/hour si 8 Fencing: 4-wire electric pasture fencing ; : : high if . : : . Continuous Grazing Maintenance: yearly inspection of the fence, conducted ; treatment other inspections regularly Source: Nielsen et al. (2005) for information on control methods, workload and number of treatments; own estimations on effectiveness of control methods. Methods Cost-benefit analysis Costs and benefits arise because invasive species interfere with the functioning of natu- ral or human-modified ecosystems which yields flows of economically valuable goods and (ecosystem) services (Emerton and Howard 2008). Cost-benefit analysis (CBA) aims to quantify the value of all positive and negative consequences of a project or measure to all members of society in monetary terms. Usually, benefits and costs accrue over extended periods (years). From today’s point of view all resources available in the future are less valuable than those available today. Therefore, in CBA future benefits (costs) are discounted relative to present benefits (costs) to obtain their present values. A benefit (cost) that occurs in year ¢ is converted to its present value by dividing it by (1+d)’ where d is the social discount rate. So if a project has a duration of 7 years with yearly benefits (B) and costs (C), the present value of the benefits (PV(B)) is PV(B)= > B, +d)’ i=0 and the present value of the costs (PV(C)) is n PVC) = °C, 1+)’ i=0 If the present value of the benefits exceeds the present value of the costs, the project is valued positively because it leads to a more efficient allocation of society’s resources (Boardman et al. 2011). The purpose of this CBA application is to compare differ- ent control measures in order to select the most efficient eradication strategy. As they can crucially influence CBA outcome, we also vary social discount rates between 1% A cost-benefit analysis of controlling giant hogweed (Heracleum mantegazzianum)... 25 and 3% (Florio and Sirtori 2013, Drupp et al. 2015).Within sensitivity analysis, we consider potential overestimation of empirically investigated benefits (scenario 1). In the second part of sensitivity analysis, we assume a worst case scenario (scenario 2), in which every German district is infested. Benefits of control measures are based on results of a choice experiment (n = 282 respondents) investigated as WTP per person and year (for further details see chapter Calculation of benefits). WTP can be regarded as indicator showing if responents are in favor or disfavor for a change from the status quo situation when comparing different alternatives (see Suppl. material 2). WTP results are particularly important where no market proxies or prices are available, as this is usually the case for public goods. In order to meet potential criticism on WTP results in terms of possible overassessment, we suggest several approaches to calibrate our WTP results. In the sensitivity analysis, we recalculate WTP results based on Ar- row et al. (1993) proposing a calibration factor of 0.5. It seems impossible to develop a unique calibration factor but we can at least compare our WTP results with other empirical studies which is done in the discussion part of this paper. Brauer and Suhr (2005) evaluated 43 empirical studies comparing hypothetical and real WTP for various environmental conservation programs. The term ‘hypotheti- cal WTP’ describes the fact that WTP is ‘just’ stated as answer in a survey situation, whereas the term ‘real WTP’ means the truly payment of the amount stated by respon- dents. The authors suggest calculating ‘switching values’ which equal WTP necessary for benefit-cost relations >1. WTP divided by ‘switching values’ identify the maximum allowed overestimation (Brauer 2002:264). The maximum allowed overestimation in the study of Brauer results in a factor of 9.38 and the switching value is 0.08 € (recrea- tion tax as average one-time payment), meaning that if respondents where only willing to pay 8 cent per day during their vacation or stated WTP was overestimated by a factor of 9, the benefits of the described program would still exceed the costs. Calculation of benefits For some public goods, such as recreation in uninfested landscapes, there are simply no market proxies for preferences. Many analysts have concluded that in this case, there is no alternative to asking a sample of people directly about their preferences (Boardman et al. 2011, Bateman et al. 2002, Hanemann 1994). Questionnaires to elicit such pre- ferences have to be prepared carefully, e.g. the formulation of valuation scenario, in- cluding sampling, and data analysis. In some countries, economically relevant benefits from eradication of invasives on direct production may arise (e.g. benefits from com- mercial crops and livestock), as well as secondary effects on other sectors and times in terms of markets and nutrition (Emerton and Howard 2008). This seems not to be the case for Germany in an economically relevant dimension (Bundesamt ftir Naturschutz 2015). In our calculations, we focus only on one benefit of eradication control: the recreational value in terms of WTP for an environment being free of giant hogweed and its risks for humans (for further benefits see Pergl et al. 2007, Nielsen et al. 2005, 26 Sandra Rajmis et al. / NeoBiota 31: 19-41 (2016) Table 3. Overview of main steps undertaken in the CBA application. Steps in CBA Definition of purpose Definition of perspective Eradication of H. mantegazzianum in Germany Compare different control measures for H. mantegazzianum; select the most effective strategy for eradication Perspective of benefits: direct use value for population from uninfested landscapes in terms of recreation value; perspective of costs: costs for implementation of eradication measures Identification of scope and scale Assumptions for time frame National level based on regional data of districts; costs: based on survey data of n = 287 districts and own calculations; benefits: survey data of n = 282 German households and own calculations Costs were calculated over a time period of 10 years; benefits were calculated as one single payment as result of a choice experiment survey for change of the status quo situation (‘willingness to pay’ for defined eradication measure per household and year) Assumptions for discount rate Definition of baseline scenario List and select control options We assume 1-3% discounting (material costs) per year, 1% increase of labor costs and 1% inflation rate per year; additionally we added an excess burden of taxation at the rate of 15% No official intervention (due to unknown/uncertain data); (uncertain) national cost estimations of average 10 million per year (Reinhardt et al. 2003) in discussion section Root destruction, mechanical cutting, chemical treatment and grazing (for further details see Table 1 and 2) Select appropriate scenarios Estimate direct costs and benefits Estimate indirect costs and benefits We calculate optimistic and pessimistic scenarios for small, medium, large, non- protected and protected areas. In the pessimistic scenario, we assume twice re- infestation within ten years; in the optimistic scenario, we assume no re-infestation after successfully conducted control measures. Chemical eradication includes costs of renaturation. Because we do not consider all measures to be successfull at once, we calculate 30% additonal costs for monitoring (ten years) and 50% additonal costs for after-treatment (each measure). Cost of labor and cost of materials (see Table 5), net present values for suggested control options within the two scenarios (see Table 6); benefits: willingness to pay of 9 Euro for measure per year and person, received from n = 282 German households Due to lacking reliable data base, no precise cost of indirect effects or side effects have been calculated. However, we address this issue. Indirect benefits are the avoided indirect cost of the baseline scenario (which we do not include here). Compare benefits and costs Perform sensitivity analysis B/C ratio was determined by comparing the costs incurred by eradication control with the benefits resulting from eradication as direct use value. The resulting ratio expresses the efficiency of the policy scenario. We calculate switching values and overestimation factors to address the reliability of WTP results (compare Brauer and Suhr 2005). Source: Summary of main CBA steps inspired by Kehlenbeck et al. (2012), Boardman et al. (2011) and Pearce et al. (2006). Pfisterer et al. 2004, Williamson and Forbes 1982). The calculation of benefits is based upon an empirical face-to-face survey using results of a choice experiment (stated pre- ference method see e.g. Adamowicz et al. 1998, Bateman et al. 2002). The main survey was preceded by qualitative preliminary studies (face-to-face; n = 16), pre-test inter- views (as mail survey and face-to-face; n = 57) and pilot study (face-to-face; n = 106). Our qualitative pre-study showed that respondents were aware of non-native plants, A cost-benefit analysis of controlling giant hogweed (Heracleum mantegazzianum)... 27 Table 4. Attributes and levels presented to respondents in the main survey. Attribute Measure Level of change (Coding in parenthesis if not directly given; *: Status Quo) Climate Sequestration/emission Sequestration/emission | Sequestration/emission ah ee Afforestation equivalents of 540 persons* equivalent of 630 equivalent of 720 5 (540) persons (630) persons (720) spe be Pepe yey ; arate oH Large scale removal if harmful or not (2) plants invasive plants particular cases (1) Insect pests | Planting site- Medium resistance and| High resistance and Low resistance and resilience (1) and storms adapted trees resilience (2)* resilience (3) General Changes in ; : : ; ao . id Medium resistance and| High resistance and ecosystem the diversity of | Low resistance and resilience (1) resilience (2)* resilience (3) resilience —_| mycorrhizal fungi Income change padi cicipereat 0 €*, 5 €, 10 €, 20 €, 35 €, 50 €, 60 €, 80 € (=coding) Price particularly the giant hogweed was mentioned in several independent interviews (open question format). Thus, we decided to use H. mantegazzianum as an indicator for in- vasive plants. To prepare respondents to the choice experiment task, there was a section in the questionnaire, were some details of the attributes and levels were explained. In the explanation we focused on the risks of giant hogweed to humans in order to justify different types of potential eradication measures. The proposed eradication measures of the attribute ‘Invasive plants’ are shown in Table 4. An examplary choice set used in the main survey is shown in Suppl. material 2. Choice cards included a picture of the H. mantegazzianum. Within the choice experi- ment, the following two options were offered to respondents: e Option 1: removal of invasive plants in particular cases for which negative effects are known, or e Option 2: large-scale removal of invasive plants even when unclear if they have negative effects or not. Respondents were asked to state their choice regarding the preferred option. In- cluding the ‘price’ (mandatory tax payment) of the hypothetical measure each choice option indicates benefits of respondents obtained by the choices. The ‘price’ for im- plementation of the proposed measures ranged from 0 to 80 Euro per programmed year. For the Status Quo situation, the cost was always zero. Statistically significant at- tribute coefficients allow for the calculation of WTP for attribute level changes. In the econometric analysis, WTP can not only be identified for a program or scenario but also for single attributes (details in Suppl. material 2). Average WTP of respondents for control measures is calculated as follows. For attributes linear in parameters, the marginal W'T’P equals the negative ratio of the respective attribute coefficient cand the coefficient of the monetary attribute c : WTP =—< Cy 28 Sandra Rajmis et al. / NeoBiota 31: 19-41 (2016) WTP values refer to one-level change in the attributes. For respondents protest- ing the choice experiment, ‘0’ WTP is assumed in order to avoid a bias in favor of higher WTP than stated in the sample. Benefits are opposed as single payment to the costs of a ten year eradication program limiting stands of H. mantegazzianum. In the following analysis WTP results for the single attribute ‘Invasive plants’ are multiplied with the number of households per infested district accounting for nationwide control measures. Calculation of costs For the cost side, we calculate two different invasion scenarios for each area size, type and measure: (i) no re-infestation after successfully conducted control measures (opti- mistic) and (ii) re-infestation twice after conducting control measures within ten years (pessimistic). Both scenarios include the suggested number of treatments per yer (up to three treatments) and measure such as displayed in Table 2. For the cost-benefit analysis, we chose the measures with lowest costs for each area type (protected or not) and size. We calculate with yearly discount rates of 1%, 2% and 3% (Florio and Sir- tori 2013, Drupp et al. 2015) and a yearly inflation rate of 1% (e.g. national bonds with expiry date of 2026, corresponding to a 10 year program starting this year, com- prising a value of 0,96%, Deutsche Bundesbank 2016). Additionally, 1% increase in labor costs per year is assumed. Both scenarios include 50% additional costs for after- treatment and 30% additional costs for monitoring (30% of labor costs) for each year. In the following, the procedure of cost calculation is briefly described (see Table 5): As hourly rate of labor costs, 33 € are calculated for all measures. For root destruc- tion measures of H. mantegazzianum, additional job training of 5 hours for instruc- tion are considered. One worker is suggested for every small area (up to 100 m’; ave- rage 50 m7’), ten workers for every medium area (>100—1,000 m’; average 550 m’), and five workers for every large area using machines (>1,000 m’; average 5,500 m’). We considered establishment costs for protective clothing, shovel, scythe and flail mower. Running costs include monitoring (30% of labor costs) and two additional treatments, plus repair costs for machines (e.g. flail mower). Costs for chemical con- trol include two treatments per area, protective clothing (safety glasses, (mouth-) mask, cap, coat and trousers, shoes and gloves), herbicide sprayer for small and me- dium areas and tractor with spraying machine for large areas, diesel and machine oil, technical inspection and machine check, glyphosate concentrate, restoration (seed mixture, e.g. 70% grass, 30% herbs, 4,000 seeds or 20 g per m’; planting costs, two cuttings per year), plough and seeder. Besides working hours for the described measures, we add five hours for job training for each area. Establishment costs for chemical control include protective clothing, shovel, scythe, machines (tractor with spraying machine, plough and seeder), herbicide sprayer, glyphosate and seeds for restoration. Running costs for chemical control are for diesel and machine oil, tech- A cost-benefit analysis of controlling giant hogweed (Heracleum mantegazzianum)... 29 Table 5. Basic assumptions for labor and material cost calculations of giant hogweed eradication measures. Description of measure Cost of labor Cost of materials 33 € per hour; additional job training Root destruction and of 5 hours, one treatment and one after- mechanical cutting nas i , mower, repair cost reatmen Protective clothing, shovel, scythe, flail 33 € per hour; additional job training | Protective clothing, machines, herbicide of 5 hours, two treatments, restoration | sprayer, diesel and machine oil, technical (plough and seeder, planting costs and inspection agency and machine check, two cuttings per year) machine repair, glyphosate Chemical treatment 33 € per hour; maintenance of fencing, periodic inspection, daily inspection of animals, moving of animals between : : Fencing, purchase of animals, shelter, fenced area, scrub removal, branch pruning, building of stiles, supplementary Water DBieadd onalodder veterinary inspection and treatment Grazing cutting outside the fencing with 1,000 hours per year and administration with 15 hours per site and year Source: Based on suggestions from Nielsen et al. (2005) and adjusted to the concrete case of eradication in the infested German districts. nical inspection and machine check. For calculations of technical agricultural cost (e.g. agricultural machines), we used KTBL software (2015). Grazing is suggested for medium (>100—1,000 m7’) and large (>1,000 m7’) infested areas. Considering sheep having to get used to H. mantegazzianum, we included an additional 5 % of total costs for initiation of the measure. We consider establishment costs as those as- sociated with the purchase of animals, fencing in a lifespan of 10 years and shelter. Running costs include maintenance of fencing, periodic inspection, and moving of animals between fenced areas as well as supplementary cutting of H. mantegazzi- anum outside the fenced area, in total, 1,000 hours (33 € per hour) workload per year. Additionally, we calculate 15 hours in administrative costs per area and year for planning, organisation and coordination of the grazing measures. Furthermore, additional fodder for the winter time as well as veterinary inspection with treatment in the case of diseases and water supply are considered. Thirty percent of total costs are suggested for yearly monitoring. Costs of labor are calculated with three people for medium areas (average 550 m’; by maximum 1,000 m’) and 5 people for large areas (average 5,500 m’*; by maximum 10,000 m7’). Assuming that the costs are fi- nanced by the public authority, we include an excess burden of taxation at the rate of 15% (see Boardman et al. 2011). The excess burden or efficiency cost of taxation recognizes that transfers between consumers, producers and the government are not costless to implement (Boardman et al. 2011). Finally, cost-effectiveness of eradica- tion strategies depend on the length of the period over which they are implemented and observed. 30 Sandra Rajmis et al. / NeoBiota 31: 19-41 (2016) Results Benefits from control measures The choice experiment was conducted as a household survey using face-to-face in- terviews in central Germany. Of the successfully contacted 302 households, 282 re- spondents completed the choice task (6.6% protest answers). An average interview took 35 minutes. Respondents preferred on average the first control option offered in the choice experiment, the ‘removal of invasive plants in particular cases for which negative effects are known’. Interviewees were willing to pay 9 € (p < 0.05) as annual contribution when compared to the more abrasive eradication program. For the 20 re- spondents (6.6% of interview respondents) protesting the choice experiment, ‘0’ WTP was assumed. Accepting a minimum advantage of invasion control for the German population living in infested districts, in terms of recreation in an environment free of giant hogweed plants, benefits amount to 238,063,641 € per year, average 829,490 € per district. To avoid overestimation, we calculated direct use values as only one single payment per household, despite WTP was investiagted as annual payment per person. The control of H. mantegazzianum, offered in two options, was identified as significant predictor of choice within the econometric model (p < 0.05; Chi* < 0.001; R? - values 0.19-0.22*). For more details on the conducted choice experiment and further results see Rajmis et al. (2009). Costs of control measures Table 6 shows the costs in terms of net present values for a ten year eradication pro- gram with varying discount rates (1%, 2% and 3%) for each proposed measure. Costs of control measures result in a total of 3.3 milion € for the optimistic invasion sce- nario and 5.8 million € for the pessimistic invasion scenario’ at a discount rate of 3%. Calculating a discount rate of 2% costs result in a total of 3.4 milion € for the optimistic invasion scenario and 6 million € for the pessimistic invasion scenario. The 1% discount rate leads to a total cost of 3.5 million € for the optimistic invasion sce- nario and 6.3 million € for the pessimistic invasion scenario. The costs for the single area types are as follows: for an optimistic scenario in non-protected areas, the low- est cost identified for small areas are root destruction with shovel and result in min. 810 € (max. 855 €), for medium areas the lowest cost resulted in chemical treatment with hand-held equipment including; which amount to min. 5,180 € (max. 5,385 €) and for large areas mechanical cutting with flail mower resulting in min. 44,631 € (max. 45,406 €). For a pessimistic scenario in non-protected and small areas lowest costs were also identified for root destruction with shovel resulting in min. 1,511 € ‘In the calculated model we received R’ - values between 0.06—0.07 which corresponds to R? - values of 0.19-—0.22 of linear models (see for details Hensher et al. 2005:338). > Costs are calculated for available data of n=287 districts (see Thiele and Otte 2008). 31 A cost-benefit analysis of controlling giant hogweed (Heracleum mantegazzianum)... P]Oq ul azIs vare ya 10y uoNdo Asadeayd a sreoX Ud} UTYIIM UOTIEISSFUT-O1 DDIM) :OLTeUDOS STAsTUNISsad p S2INSEIUT [OIIUOD PaIoNpuod AT[Nyssaoons Joye UOTeISIJUI-3I OU :oLFeUADS SNsTUIIdO 9 seore aie] = JT ‘seore UNIpou = YJ ‘seose ][euUs = $ q 37€J JUNODSICT & ZS10¥F| ZZ9‘TF| OLS EF “ssa ‘ LOL‘TT| Z9OEET | LOFT do 689°ST | OFZ9T | FESO “ssaq i FUV'L dO *SSOq do : C ¢ ‘ ‘ (3 ge ¢ *SSOq il iach [Pa ian a | OSTSA | 6Ze%s peace | =f =e fe | cere so | ayy4os YIM PPAoys yIIM Spenese OZIS Surgnd peorueysey| uoRNonIsepjooy | * vary ‘steak Ud} JO porjad-own & JOJ seare poisazUl JO somnsvouT [oIIUOD parsasZns Joy (sanfeA JUasoid Jou) s1SOD *g BIGUL 32 Sandra Rajmis et al. / NeoBiota 31: 19-41 (2016) (max. 1,628 €), for medium areas chemical treatment with hand-held equipment in- cluding restoration at a min. price of 11,028 € (max. 11,832 €), for large areas the lowest cost were reached by grazing with a min. of 49,251 € (max. 52,850 €). For an optimistic scenario in small protected areas, lowest costs are also reached by root de- struction with shovel and amount to min. 810 € (max. 855 €), for medium areas the lowest cost result for mechanical cutting with scythe amounting to min. 7,424 € (max. 7,727 €). For large areas mechanical cutting with scythe is suggested which amounts to min. cost of 22,707 € (max. 24,071 €). For the pessimistic scenario in protected and small areas the lowest cost result in root destruction with shovel and amount to min. costs of 1,511 € (max. 1,628 €) for medium areas mechanical cutting with scythe resulting in min. cost of 15,658 € (max. 16,834 €), and for large areas (mechanical cutting with scythe as well) in min. cost of 40,157 € (max. 43,310 €). Some details of scenario calculations are shown in the supplementary material (Suppl. material 1). Benefit-cost relation of control measures and sensitivity analysis We chose the measures with lowest costs for each area type (protected or not) and size (small, medium and large) for the final calculation. The lowest cost measures are root destruction with shovel in small areas (optimistic and pessimistic scenario), chemi- cal treatment with hand-held equipment in medium areas (optimistic and pessimistic scenario), mechanical cutting with flail mower in large areas (optimistic scenario), and grazing for large areas in the pessimistic scenario. Root destruction with shovel and mechanical cutting with scythe are due to legal constraints the only options for pro- tected areas. The benefit-cost relation of German districts for control measures of H. mantegazzianum lies between 69:1 (discount rate of 1%) and 72:1 (discount rate of 3%) for optimistic scenario and 38:1 (discount rate of 1%) and 41:1 (discount rate of 3%) for pessimistic scenario calculations for each area size. Results indicate that every euro of calculated costs can be opposed to averagely 55 € of benefits (discount rates between 1% and 3%). To give consideration to the earlier mentioned concerns of potential overestimations, we calculate the maximum allowed overestimation (Brauer 2002, Brauer and Suhr 2005). Switching values range between 0,02 and 0,03 € (average 2,5 cent) in Scenario 1 and between 0,24 and 0,30 € (average 26 cent) in Scenario 2. This is the amount necessary to result in a benefit-cost relation >1. Calculating the net-benefit of measure implementation (WTP/switching value), a factor of 448 results for optimistic and 299 for pessimistic scenario calculations. This means, if our empirically investigated results would be overestimated by factors between 299 (pessimistic scenario) and 448 (opti- mistic scenario), ‘necessary’ real WTP would be still the amount of the switching va- lues (0.03 € and 0.02 €), hence high enough to keep the benefit-cost relation positive. Since the utilized source of data (Thiele and Otte 2008) may not represent the current state of invasion status in Germany, we also provide a sensitivity analysis in terms of infestation assumptions (Scenario 2). We assume that every German district is A cost-benefit analysis of controlling giant hogweed (Heracleum mantegazzianum)... 33 Table 7. Scenario 1. Benefit-cost relation of infested German districts (N= 287) based on data from Thiele and Otte (2008) and overestimation factor of WTP results. Results Optimistic scenario Pessimistic scenario Discount rate (DR) 1% 3% Average benefit-cost relation of 68.65 38.06 40.96 German districts Switching value (in €) 0.02 0.03 Maximum allowed overestimation 448 299 (WTP/switching value) Table 8. Scenario 2. Benefit-cost relation of worst case scenario: every German district (N= 440) infested and overestimation factor of WIP results. Results Pessimistic scenario Discount rate (DR) 1% 2% 3% Average benefit-cost relation of German districts She 4.0 4.2 Switching value (in €) 0.30 0.25 0.24 Maximum allowed overestimation (WTP/switching value) 29.9 Sete) Yes infested with at least one small, one medium and one large area and calculate the pessi- mistic infestation scenario without chemical treatment (due to possible infested nature reserves or other sensitive landscape areas), control cost amount to 57 and 61 million euro for ten years of treatment. As this is a worst case scenario, we assume the most expensive cost for each measure and area size here. This cost estimate is well within the range of similar calculations for other countries (Reinhardt et al. 2003, Sampson 1994, van Wilgen et al. 2004). The cost estimates of Gren et al. (2009) are somewhat higher than our results (see below). Opposed to the benefits of our survey with one single payment per German household in the infested districts, this results in a benefit cost-relation of 4:1. The maximum allowed overestimation ranges between 30 and 37 and is thus lower as in scenario 1 (between 38 and 72). This result seems reasoned due to average benefit-cost relation in scenario 2 is ten times lower (e.g. 4 versus 40 using DR of 2%) comparing pessimistic scenario calculations. Switching values range between 0,24 and 0,30 €, meaning that even if WTP would have been be overesti- mated 37 times, we would still have a benefit-cost relation >1. As mentioned earlier, the NOAA Panel suggests calibrating empirical WTP results by a factor of 0.5 (Arrow et al. 1993). If we recalculate scenario 1 with halved WTP, the allowed overestimation is 50% reduced and results in a factor of 150 considering pessimistic assumptions and a factor of 225 for optimistic assumptions. For scenario 2, the allowed overestimation with halved WTP has still a factor of 17, meaning that even if WTP would have been stated 17 times higher then conceived by respondents, we would still have a benefit- cost relation >1. 34 Sandra Rajmis et al. / NeoBiota 31: 19-41 (2016) Discussion Our cost-benefit-analysis clearly shows that control measures limiting H. mantagez- zianum in infested German districts are efficient from an economic point of view. The most promising measures from the control perspective are root cutting and chemical treatment by hand-held equipment or machinery, although chemical control inclu- des two treatments and revegetation. Root cutting is an important control measure for protected areas. These findings are in line with experiences from Latvia (Olukalns 2007) and United Kingdom (Sampson 1994; see below). If the suggested measures are implemented successfully including after-treatment, the probability of re-infestation is low and the measures may have a very positive benefit-cost ratio in the long term as well. Reducing monitoring frequency increases yearly costs up to 162% (Breukers et al. 2008). Net present values of control measures range between 810 € for root destruction with shovel (DR of 3%) and 385 thousand € (DR of 1%) for chemical treatment with machines for a time period of ten years depending on area size and type of treatment or 4 and 8 cent per capita in Germany for all necessary control measures. The cost have to be recognized as lower limit of minimum necessary eradication cost. The identified benefits of our survey are approximately 9 Euro per capita in Germany, resulting in a benefit cost-relation of 225:1 (lowest cost within 1% DR) and 113:1 (highest cost within 3% DR). If we consider just one person per German household willing to pay, the benefit-cost relation lies between 113:1 and 56:1. By the way, this is again equiva- lent to a 50% reduction of our WTP results, which is suggested by the NOAA-panel as factor of calibration (Arrow et al. 1993). Especially the cost estimates are somewhat lower in comparison to the calculations for other countries. The benefit cost-results are in the dimension of van Wilgen et al. (2004). Unfortunately, there are very few studies about costs and benefits of invasion control. In the following, available cost estimations on invasion control scenarios are pre- sented and — if possible — compared to the findings of our cost-benefit analysis. The only economic assessment of giant hogweed eradication cost especially for Germany can be found in Reinhardt et al. (2003). The authors estimate annual control cost of giant hogweed in Germany amounting to average 12 million euro, including 1 million euro for medical treatment of injured humans, 1.2 million euro for measures in nature reserves, 2.1 million for measures in road management, 2.4 million for measures in municipal management and 5.6 million euro for district management measures (no further differentiation of costs). If we assume a minimum infestation of each area size and type in the surveyed districts (n = 287) and add the (uncertain) current cost of about 12 million spent in Germany for yearly giant hogweed eradication (Reinhardt et al. 2003) for a ten year eradication program in our analysis and compare the benefits for only one year to the cost results, the benefit-cost relation ist still 2:1. The resulting values still demonstrate an environmental improvement and welfare improvement for the society even if we look at more costly invasion scenarios. Gren et al. (2009) estimated the total costs of 13 invasive species in Sweden. All species are subject to control by Swedish public authorities, and estimates for most A cost-benefit analysis of controlling giant hogweed (Heracleum mantegazzianum)... cB) invasive species include either damage cost or actual control cost. ‘The results indicate a total annual cost between approximately 153 million € and 479 million €, which correspond to 17 euro and 53 € per capita in Sweden. The total annual cost for giant hogweed control range from 38 thousand € to 47 thousand € (0.004 to 0.005 € per capita in Sweden). In our study, annual control cost per measure type and size range between 81 € and 39 thousand € (up to 0.0005 € per capita in Germany), which is in the lower limit of Gren et al. (2009). Sampson (1994) estimated control cost of giant hogweed in UK for 150 infested sites identified by a postal survey conducted in 1990. The three main adopted control strategies were: cutting plus glyphosate, cutting alone or glyphosate alone. Overall expenditure of control costs for 1989 range between approximately 148 € and 42.630 € (historical exchange values from 2000; 1989 not available). These results are in the same dimension of our calculations for control measures of n = 396 infested sites ran- ging between 810 € and 385 thousand €, that is 1 € to 284 € per site in UK versus 2 € to 972 € per site in Germany. In the study of van Wilgen et al. (2004), costs and benefits from biological control of six invasive alien weed species (e.g. red sesbania and jointed cactus) in South Africa are compared. Red sesbania replaces indigenous riverine and wetland species, espe- cially the seeds are poisonous and lethal to mammals, birds and reptiles. The jointed cactus competes with indigenous species as well. Dense infestations reduce the grazing potential (up to 90%) and hence the value of the agricultural land. The authors calcu- late benefits as economic losses in water use, biodiversity, and preservation of the value of agricultural land. Benefit-cost ratios range from 8:1 for the red sesbania (Sesbania punicea) to 709:1 for the jointed cactus (Opuntia aurantiaca Lindley). The sensitivity analysis showes that the returns on investment in biological control generally remain positive with some variations between species (van Wilgen et al. 2004). In our study, we did neither include benefits as economic losses from values of agricultural land nor biodiversity deducting that our benefit estimates are rather underestimated than overestimated. Conclusions The studies mentioned above result in positive benefit-cost outcomes indicating that invasion control is sensefull from an economic point of view: the control activities are economically efficient and they have in large part positive effects on biodiversity, water use, human and animal health. This might be a more convincing argument for policymakers than nature conservation as good achievement. Since the EU regulation 1143/2014 entered into force, member states are anyway obligated to conduct cost- benefit analysis to identify cost efficient control measures. However, we quantified just one benefit of giant hogweed control in terms of direct use value for recreation; there might be much more benefits which we did not include. The true benefits of giant hogweed control to society might be much higher. Compared to the studies in this 36 Sandra Rajmis et al. / NeoBiota 31: 19-41 (2016) discussion section, we conclude that our results might reveal only the lower limit of control costs. Based on our findings and the review literature, we suggest for future control programs: ¢ to support research on prevention methods in different ecosystems e.g. biodiversity conservation at landscape level as invasion insurance e incorporate non-market values such as loss in aesthetic values, recreation or other ecosystem services as benefit of control programs; ¢ to plan control measures at an adequate spatial scale taking into account potential re-infestations. Acknowledgements We thank German Research Foundation (DFG Research Training Group 1086) for funding, our field assistants, the survey participants, J. Barkmann, H. Kehlenbeck, U. Starfinger and J. Hoffmann and two anonymous reviewers for providing valuable criti- cism on a previous version of this manuscript, as well a M. Harcken for language editing. References Adamowicz W, Louviere J, Swait J (1998) Introduction to Attribute-Based Stated Choice Methods. Advanis Inc. for the National Oceanic and Atmospheric Administration, US Departement of Commerce, Edmonton. Andersen UV, Calov B (1996) Long-term effects of sheep grazing on giant hogweed (Heracleum mantegazzianum). Hydrobiologia 340: 277-284. doi: 10.1007/BF00012768 Arrow KJ, Solow R, Portney PR, Leamer EE, Radner R, Schumann H (1993) Report on the NOAA Panel on contingent valuation. Federal Register 58: 4602-4614. Bateman IJ, Carson RT, Day B, Hanemann M, Hanley N, Hett T, Jones-Lee M, Loomes G, Mourato S, Ozdemiroglu E, Pearce OBE DW, Sugden R, Swanson J (2002) Econom- ic valuation with Stated Preference Techniques: A manual. Edward Elgar, Cheltenham, 458 pp. doi: 10.4337/9781781009727 Boardman AE, Greenberg DH, Vining AR, Weimer DL (2011) Cost-benefit analysis, concepts and practice. Prentice Hall, Boston, 560 pp. Brauer I (2002) Artenschutz aus volkswirtschaftlicher Sicht. Die Nutzen-Kosten-Analyse als Entscheidungshilfe. Metropolis, Marburg, 322 pp. Brauer I, Suhr A (2005) Ergebnisse von Zahlungsbereitschaftsanalysen: Interpretation und Ver- wendung. In: Margeraf R, Brauer I, Fischer A, Menzel S, Stratmann U, Suhr A (Eds) Oko- nomische Bewertung bei umweltrelevanten Entscheidungen. Metropolis, Marburg, 149-183. Breukers A, Mourits M, van der Werf W, Lansink AO (2008) Costs and benefits of controlling quarantine diseases: a bio-economic modeling approach. Agricultural Economics 38: 137-149. doi: 10.1111/j.1574-0862.2008.00288.x A cost-benefit analysis of controlling giant hogweed (Heracleum mantegazzianum)... 37 Bundesamt flr Naturschutz (2015) Gebietsfremde und invasive Arten in Deutschland. Hera- cleum mantegazzianum. http://neobiota.bfn.de/12641.html [accessed 8 April 2015] Buttenschon RM, Nielsen C (2007) Control of Heracleum mantegazzianum by grazing. In: Pysek P, Cock MJW, Nentwig W, Ravn HP (Eds) Ecology and Management of giant hogweed (Heracleum mantegazzianum). CAB International, Wallingford, 240-254. doi: 10.1079/9781845932060.0240 Camm E, Buck HW, Mitchell JC (1976) Phytophotodermatitis from Heracleum mantegazzi- anum. Contact dermatitis 2: 68-72. doi: 10.1111/j.1600-0536.1976.tb02987.x Deutsche Bundesbank (2016) Kurse und Renditen bérsennotierter Bundeswertpapiere. https:// www.bundesbank.de/Redaktion/DE/Downloads/Service/Bundeswertpapiere/Rendite/kurse_ renditen_bundeswertpapiere_2016_04.pdf?__blob=publicationFile [accessed 6 April 2016] Drever JC, Hunter JA (1970) Giant hogweed dermatitis. Scottish Medical Journal 15: 315-319. Drupp M, Freeman M, Groom B, Nesje F (2015) Discounting disentangled. Working Pa- per No. 172, Grantham Research Institute on Climate Change and the Environment, London. Emerton L, Howard G (2008) A Toolkit for the Economic Analysis of Invasive Species. Global Invasive Species Programme Nairobi. European and Mediterranean Plant Protection Organization (2009) EPPO data sheet on In- vasive Plants. http://onlinelibrary.wiley.com/doi/10.1111/j.1365-338.2009.02313.x/pdf [accessed 7 April 2015] European Commission (2014) EU regulation 1143/2014 on invasive alien species. Official Journal of the European Union 317/35. http://data.europa.eu/eli/reg/2014/1143/oj [accessed 13 May 2015] European Environment Agency (2012) A review of streamlining European biodiversity (SEBI) Indicator 10. http://www.eea.europa.eu/publications/streamlining-european-biodiversi- ty-indicators-sebi Florio M, Sirtori E (2013) The Social Cost of Capital: Recent Estimates for the EU Countries. http://ssrn.com/abstract=2723379 [accessed 4 April 2016] Genovesi P, Shine C (2003) European Strategy on Invasive Alien Species. Convention on the conservation of European wildlife and natural habitats. Council of Europe Publishing, Strasbourg. Gren I-M, Isacs L, Carlsson M (2009) Costs of alien invasive species in Sweden. AMBIO 38: 135-140. doi: 10.1579/0044-7447-38.3.135 Hanemann WM (1994) Valuing the environment through contingent valuation. Journal of Economic Perspectives 8: 19-43. doi: 10.1257/jep.8.4.19 Henry P, Lay G, Goudet J, Guisan A, Jahodova S$, Besnard G (2009) Reduced genetic di- versity, increased isolation and multiple introductions of invasive giant hogweed in the western Swiss Alps. Journal Molecular Ecology 18: 2819-2831. doi: 10.1111/j.1365- 294X.2009.04237.x Hipkin C (1991) Phytophotodermatitis. Botanical Society of the British Isles News 59: 7-8. Holzmann C, Thiele J, Buttschardt TK (2014) Neophyten-Management am Beispiel des Riesen-Barenklaus — Bedingungen erfolgreicher Bekampfung von Heracleum mantegazzia- num. Naturschutz und Landschaftsplanung 46: 79-85. 38 Sandra Rajmis et al. / NeoBiota 31: 19-41 (2016) Hiils J, Otte A, Eckstein RL (2007) Population life-cycle and stand structure in dense and open stands of the introduced tall herb Heracleum mantegazzianum. Biological Invasions 9: 799-811. doi: 10.1007/s10530-006-9082-9 Jalas J (1955) Hemerobie und hemerochore Pflanzenarten. Ein terminologischer Reformver- such. Acta Societatis pro Fauna et Flora Fennica 72: 11-15. Kahmen A, Perner J, Audorff V, Weisser W, Buchmann N (2005) Effects of plant diversity, community composition and environmental parameters on productivity in montane Euro- pean grasslands. Oecologia 142: 606-615. doi: 10.1007/s00442-004-1749-2 Kehlenbeck H, Cannon R, Breukers A, Battisti A, Leach A, Mumford J, MacLeod A (2012) A protocol for analysing the costs and benefits of phytosanitary measures. Bulletin OEPP/ EPPO 42: 81-88. doi: 10.1111/j.1365-2338.2011.02524.x Kennedy TA, Naeem S, Howe KM, Knops JMH, Tilman D, Reich PB (2002) Biodiversity as a barrier to ecological invasion. Nature 417: 636-638. doi: 10.1038/nature00776 Kowarik I (2010) Biologische Invasionen. Neophyten und Neozoen in Mitteleuropa. 2., erwei- terte Auflage. Ulmer, Stuttgart, 492 pp. Longo G, Seidler TG, Garibaldi LA, Tognetti PM, Chaneton EJ (2013) Functional group dominance and identity effects influence the magnitude of grassland invasion. Journal of Ecology 101: 1114-1124. doi: 10.1111/1365-2745.12128 Machado A (2004) An index of naturalness. Journal for Nature Conservation 12: 95-110. doi: 10.1016/j.jnc.2003.12.002 Maguire CM, Cosgrove PJ, Kelly J (2008) Best Practice Management Guidelines, giant hogweed, Heracleum mantegazzianum. Prepared for NIEA and NPWS as part of Invasive Species Ireland. Moore JL, Mouquet N, Lawton JH, Loreau M (2001) Coexistence, saturation and invasion resistance in simulated plant assemblages. Oikos 94: 303-314. doi: 10.1034/j.1600- 0706.2001.94021 1.x Mwangi PN, Schmitz M, Scherber C, Roscher C, Schumacher J, Scherer-Lorenzen M, Weisser WW, Schmid B (2007) Niche pre-emption increases with species richness in experimental plant communities. Journal of Ecology 95: 65-78. doi: 10.1111/j.1365- 2745.2006.01189.x Naeem S, Knops JMH, Tilman D, Howe KM, Kennedy T, Gale S (2000) Plant diversity increases resistance to invasion in the absence of covarying extrinsic factors. Oikos 91: 97-108. doi: 10.1034/j.1600-0706.2000.910108.x Nehring S, Essl F, Rabitsch W (2013a) Methodik der naturschutzfachlichen Invasivitatsbewer- tung ftir gebietsfremde Arten. BEN-Skripten 340, Bundesamt ftir Naturschutz, Bonn, 46 pp. Nehring S, Kowarik I, von der Lippe M, Lauterbach D, Seitz B, Isermann M, Etling K (2013b) Naturschutzfachliche Invasivitatsbewertungen ftir in Deutschland wild lebende gebiets- fremde Gefaf$pflanzen. I. Einfihrung, Auswertung und Schlussfolgerungen. BfN-Skrip- ten, Bundesamt ftir Naturschutz, Bonn, 9-28. Netzwerk Phytodiversitat Deutschland [NetPhyD], Bundesamt ftir Naturschutz [BfN] (2013) Verbreitungsatlas der Farn-und Bliitenpflanzen Deutschlands. Landwirtschaftsverlag, Miinster, 912 pp. Nicholas AP, Ronald EW, Darbyshire SJ, Mulligan GA (2005) The Biology of Invasive Alien Plants in Canada. 4. Heracleum mantegazzianum Sommier & Levier. Canadian Journal of Plant Science 86: 69-589. A cost-benefit analysis of controlling giant hogweed (Heracleum mantegazzianum)... a9 Nielsen C, Ravn HP, Nentwig W, Wade M (2005) The giant hogweed best practice manual. Guidelines for the management and control of an invasive weed in Europe. http://www. giant-alien.dk/pdf/Giant_alien_uk.pdf [accessed 20 April 2015] Nielsen C, Vanaga I, Treikale O, Priekule I (2007) Mechanical and chemical control of Hera- cleum mantegazzianum and H. sosnowskyi. In: Pysek P, Cock MJW, Nentwig W, Ravn HP (Eds) Ecology and management of giant hogweed (Heracleum mantegazzianum). CAB International, Wallingford, 226-239. doi: 10.1079/9781845932060.0226 Noxious Weed Control Program (2015) King County Noxious Weed List. Giant hogweed (Heracleum mantegazzianum). http://your.kingcounty.gov/dnrp/library/water-and-land/ weeds/BMPs/hogweed-control.pdf [accessed 10 April 2015] Olukalns A (2007) Eradication of Giant Hogweed Sosnowskyi (Heracleum sosnowskyi) in Latvia. European Weed Research Society, 14° EWRS Symposium, June 2007, Norway (Hamar). Pearce D, Atkinson G, Mourato S (2006) Cost-benefit analysis and the environment: recent developments. OECD publishing, Paris, 318 pp. Pergl J, Hiils J, Perglova I, Eckstein RL, Pysek P, Otte A (2007) Population dynamics of Heracleum mantegazzianum. In: Pysek P, Cock MJW, Nentwig W, Ravn HP (Eds) Ecol- ogy and Management of giant hogweed (Heracleum mantegazzianum). CAB International, Wallingford, 92-111. doi: 10.1079/9781845932060.0092 Pergl J, Perglova I, Pysek P (2012) Heracleum mantegazzianum Sommier & Levier (giant hog- weed). In: Francis RA (Ed.) A handbook of global freshwater invasive species. Earthscan, London, 57-65. Pfisterer AB, Joshi J, Schmid B, Fischer M (2004) Rapid decay of diversity-productivity rela- tionships after invasion of experimental plant communities. Basic and Applied Ecology 5: 5-14. doi: 10.1078/1439-1791-00215 Pokorny ML, Sheley RL, Zabinski CA, Engel RE, Sevjcar TJ, Borkowski JJ (2005) Plant func- tional group diversity as a mechanism for invasion resistance. Restoration Ecology 13: 448-459. doi: 10.1111/j.1526-100X.2005.00056.x Pysek P (1991) Heracleum mantegazzium in the Czech Republic: dynamics of spreading from the historical perspective. Folia Geobotanica 26: 439-454. doi: 10.1007/BF02912779 Rajmis S, Barkmann J, Marggraf R (2009) User community preferences for climate change mitigation and adaptation measures around Hainich National Park, Germany. Climate Research 40: 61-73. doi: 10.3354/cr00803 Reinhardt F, Herle M, Bastiansen F, Streit B (2003) Okonomische Folgen der Ausbreitung von Neobiota. Umweltbundesamt, Forschungsbericht 201 86 211, Dessau, 248 pp. Sampson C (1994) Cost and impact of current control methods used against Heracleum man- tegazzianum (giant hogweed) and the case for instigating a biological control programme. In: Waal LC de, Child LE, Wade PM, Brock JH (Eds) Ecology and management of invasive riverside plants. John Wiley & Sons, Chichester, 55-65. Starfinger U, Kowarik I (2003) Heracleum mantegazzianum Sommier & Levier (Apiaceae), Riesen- Barenklau. Bundesamt ftir Naturschutz. http://www.neobiota.de [accessed 29 June 2015] Steinhardt U, Herzog F, Lausch A, Miiller E, Lehmann S (1999) Hemeroby index for lands- cape monitoring and evaluation. In: Pykh YA, Hyatt DE, Lenz RJ (Eds) Environmental Indices. System Analysis Approach. EOLSS, Oxford, 237-254. 40 Sandra Rajmis et al. / NeoBiota 31: 19-41 (2016) Thiele J, Isermann M, Otte A, Kollmann J (2010) Competitive displacement or biotic resist- ance? Disentangling relationships between community diversity and invasion success of tall herbs and shrubs. Journal of Vegetation Science 21: 213-220. doi: 10.1111/j.1654- 1103.2009.01139.x Thiele J, Otte A (2008) Invasion patterns of Heracleum mantegazzianum in Germany on the regional and landscape scales. Journal for Nature Conservation 16: 61—71. doi: 10.1016/j. jnc.2007.08.002 Thiele J, Otte A (2006) Analysis of habitats and communities invaded by Heracleum mantegaz- zianum Somm. et Lev. (giant hogweed) in Germany. Phytocoenologia 36: 281-320. doi: 10.1127/0340-269X/2006/0036-0281 Tiley GED, Philp B (1994) Heracleum mantegazzianum (giant hogweed) and its control in Scotland. In: de Waal LC, Child L, Wade PM, Brock JH (Eds) Ecology and management of invasive riverside plants. Wiley and Sons, Chichester, 101-109. United Nations Environment Program [UNEP] (2015) Invasive Alien Species. Convention on Biological Diversity (CBD). http://www.cbd.int/invasive [accessed 7 April 2015] Van Ruijven J, De Deyn GB, Berendse F (2003) Diversity reduces invasibility in experi- mental plant communities: the role of plant species. Ecology Letters 6: 910-918. doi: 10.1046/j.1461-0248.2003.00516.x Van Wilgen BW, de Wit MP, Anderson HJ, Le Maitre DC, Kotze IM, Ndala S, Brown B, Rapholo MB (2004) Costs and benefits of biological control of invasive alien species: case studies from South Africa. South African Journal of Science 100: 113-122. Wang J, Ge Y, Zhang CB, Bai Y, Du ZK (2013) Dominant Functional Group Effects on the Invasion Resistance at Different Resource Levels. PLoS ONE 8:e77220. doi: 10.1371/ journal.pone.0077220 Westhus W, Fritzlar F, Klaus S, Nollert A, Wiesner J, Knorre D, von Zimmermann W, Miller R (2006) Bedrohen invasive gebietsfremde Tiere und Pflanzen unsere heimische Natur? Ein Situationsbericht aus Thiiringen. Landschaftspflege und Naturschutz in Thiiringen 43: 1-19. Williamson JA, Forbes JC (1982) Giant hogweed Heracleum mantegazzianum: its spread and control with glyphosate in amenity areas. British Crop Protection Conference Weeds 3: 967-972. A cost-benefit analysis of controlling giant hogweed (Heracleum mantegazzianum)... 4] Supplementary material | Details of scenario cost calculations Authors: Sandra Rajmis, Jan Thiele, Rainer Marggraf Data type: Adobe PDF file Explanation note: In Suppl. material 1 we present some cost calculation details of dif- ferent infested area types and sizes. Copyright notice: This dataset is made available under the Open Database License (http://opendatacommons.org/licenses/odbl/1.0/). The Open Database License (ODDbL) is a license agreement intended to allow users to freely share, modify, and use this Dataset while maintaining this same freedom for others, provided that the original source and author(s) are credited. Supplementary material 2 Exemplary choice set and details of scenario benefit calculations Authors: Sandra Rajmis, Jan Thiele, Rainer Marggraf Data type: Adobe PDF file Explanation note: In Suppl. material 2 we present an exemplary choice set used in the choice experiment and some details of econometric analysis. Copyright notice: This dataset is made available under the Open Database License (http://opendatacommons.org/licenses/odbl/1.0/). The Open Database License (ODDbL) is a license agreement intended to allow users to freely share, modify, and use this Dataset while maintaining this same freedom for others, provided that the original source and author(s) are credited.